STRAIGHT TALK ON AGRICULTURE
A Conversation with Mark Ritchie
Mark Ritchie
is Agricultural Trade Policy Analyst for the Minnesota Department of Agriculture
and the co-chair of the League of Rural Voters. He is author of Crisis
by Design: A Brief Review of U.S. Farm Policy and Loss of Family Farms:
Inevitable Result or Conscious Policy?, as well as numerous articles and
essays on farm policy, agricultural trade and environmental issues in
agriculture. Ritchie spoke with Multinational Monitor recently about the
drought and other issues confronting family farmers in the 1980s. Excerpts
from the conversation appear below.
Multinational Monitor: How are commodity prices determined today?
Mark Ritchie: In the 1930s, with the coming of [Franklin Delano]
Roosevelt, the first major national farm legislation was passed and signed.
The legislation was based on some of the ideas that arose out of the Populist
Party in the 1890s. The most important features of the basic farm programs
as they existed in the '30s, and continue to exist today, had to do with
price floors, price ceilings and supply management. The government created
an agency called the Commodity Credit Corporation [CCC] which was a government
agency. At first it was quasi-private but it is now totally a government
agency, which has the responsibility of assisting farmers in balancing
the ups and downs of the commodity markets during the year.
What typically happens in the U.S. [is] almost all the farmers harvest
their main crops in the span of about 30 days in October and November
of each year. That means that 12 months of supply comes onto the market
in a one-month period of time. Logically, it will depress and push the
market and prices very low during that period of time. Because of this,
the grain companies have always been able to wait until those couple months
of a year, [when] farmers need to sell because they need money to repay
their loans, they need to have money to cover their taxes, they don't
have the storage. So the grain companies [can] buy all of their crops
in the fall of the year when prices [are] very low, and then sit it out
until next year and then not have to pay farmers a more normal market
price because they were able to buy most of what they needed during distressed
times in the fall.
So what the government did was create an agency that said to farmers,
if the price falls below a certain predetermined level, and that level
is determined by Congress, you can come into our local office, which is
in every county of the U.S., and you can borrow a certain amount of money
against each bushel that you produced. This is called the 'loan rate.'
And we will loan you this money and when prices recover you can repay
the loan with interest.... [I]n the 1930s ... the loan rate establish[ed]
a minimum or a floor price at roughly the cost of production. The way
it would work was if the corporations started bidding the price down below
this pre-determined level, once it hit that level farmers would go to
their local CCC office and borrow that much against their crop. So essentially,
they no longer had the pressure on them to sell their crop to the grain
companies, because they'd borrowed money, they could pay their bills,
they could send their kids off to school and do whatever they needed.
And then when the grain companies decided they wanted the grain, they
would bid the price back up above that level, and when it reached a certain
point, farmers would sell the grain to the grain companies, take the money
and repay the loan from the government with interest. So this was the
kind of basic floor support loan policy and program. It's been in effect
since the 1930s and it's been a very effective program. In fact, for the
commodities for which this program has existed, and in general it has
been for most of the major grains and cereals--corn, wheat, soybeans,
cotton, rye, sorghum, a whole number of crops-- this floor price, when
in effect, has set, more or less, the market price. You can look over
the 30-40 year time, and you'll see that the market price stays just above
this minimum price set by Congress. Of course, when you have some emergency
situations, like the drought, or the Russian wheat deal, you can see some
very sharp rises and fluctuations. But in general this price establishes
the market price for commodities.
Now, also during the 1930s, farmers were not only worried [about] maintaining
some kind of minimum price, but also there were droughts and dustbowls,
just like we have today, and the grain companies who owned the grain during
those periods of shortages were able to raise the price dramatically,
as they will try to do today. Farmers at that time and even today are
either the largest or almost the largest consumers of their own products.
Cattle producers buy a lot of the corn, chicken producers buy a lot of
the soybean meal. In the 1920s and 1930s oats were a major crop because
they were feed for horses, which were used for farming. So farmers were
also very concerned, as were city people, about the effects of shortages
on price increases. And so they built a ceiling price into the farm program,
also. If the grain companies during times of shortage tried to raise the
price and charge people very high prices for the commodities, the government
maintained reserve food stocks, which [it] would then release onto the
market very slowly to bring that price down and keep it in a fairly narrow
range. So the government was intervening both to support prices nearly
at the cost of production at the bottom, and they were intervening to
release stocks onto the market to keep a ceiling on prices. This had a
couple of important effects. One, of course, is it kept consumer prices
very low and stable. But it also tended to restrict speculation ... particularly
speculation, for example, on the Chicago Board of Trade or that kind of
commodities speculation, where the money is made by sharp price springs.
Now the third element of this farm program of the 1930s was one in which
there was a recognition that if there were many years of very good weather
in a row--along with technological advancements--that farmers would tend
to produce larger and larger crops ... Surpluses buil[t] up at different
times, and if you didn't have a mechanism by which the government helped
farmers to reduce their production when there were times of surplus you
would tend to build up mountains of corn, and the government would be
the buyer of last resort [and] you'd have high taxpayer costs. There are
many problems which come from times of surplus production and times of
surplus storage. So they instituted a series of supply management programs,
where the government would take a poll of the farmers, a referendum, a
vote, and based on the approval of the farmers, the government would implement
a percentage reduction of the production, to help bring supply in line
with demand.
So these three elements, price floor, price ceiling and supply management,
were the key components of that program in the 1930s and 40s. But in the
early 1950s we saw a throwing out, the abolishing of this program. And
it was the end result of a very intense lobbying effort by the corporations.
Keep in mind that although this particular program was quite good for
farmers and very good for rural communities, and was at a time when there
was an explosion of soil conservation efforts--there were a lot of good
things that came out of this set of policies--it tended to be viewed unfavorably
by the same segments of the business community farmers faced in the 1800s.
For those corporations who supplied chemicals, fertilizers, seed, tractors,
etc., they viewed the supply management provisions as somehow restricting
their sales. The farmers were reducing their plantings of wheat by 10
percent, a supplier could then argue that they were selling 10 percent
less wheat seed, 10 percent less chemicals, 10 percent less fertilizer,
etc. So they viewed it as a restriction on their ability to sell more
products. At the same time, the companies [that] were buying grain to
sell it overseas or to turn into breakfast cereal viewed government intervention
to maintain a minimum price the same way that industrial corporations
viewed the government intervening to set minimum standards for labor--they
opposed it. They believed that it drove up their cost of corn, or meat,
or whatever, [and] that it was in some way restricting their ability to
make a profit. Now these forces combined in a very intense lobbying effort.
And that effort culminated in the early 1950s, and although it was fairly
unsuccessful in the 1940s, basically arguing that we should throw farmers
to the free market, most people didn't believe that was going to be a
better solution. But in the early 1950s these opponents of this program--the
Roosevelt farm programs, or the Parity farm programs, as they were called--
picked up on a new tactic, which was to label the Roosevelt era programs--not
just farm programs but others, but especially the farm programs as being
'socialist,' 'Bolshevik,' 'central planning' in agriculture. They used
this terminology, and tied it in with the overall McCarthy era, the red-baiting
era, this whole anti-communist hysteria, and turned that into their main
tool for getting this program abolished. And in 1952 and 1953, in the
Eisenhower administration under the leadership of Ezra Taft Benson, who
was the secretary of agriculture, the Roosevelt farm program was essentially
abolished.
In the first couple years, they attempted to mask the change by describing
it as more flexible. In fact they called the new farm program the 'Flexible
Parity Program.' But what this essentially meant was they were removing
the strong, effective supply management provisions so that there was a
tendency to build up surpluses, and they gave the secretary of agriculture
the authority to lower the prices in hopes of making 'the U.S. more competitive.'
From the early 1950s to the early 1970s we went through a real roller
coaster and chaotic period in U.S. farm policy. Year after year, we would
have an unstable situation where some years we would build up surpluses
and some years the government would feel so compelled to act that they
would shut down whole counties. We had the land bank program at that time,
where a whole county would be shut down and couldn't farm. But by 1970,
1971, 1972, it became clear that this was just too chaotic to continue
this kind of roller coaster effect, and the government began to debate
farm policy again in a serious way. The farmers basically said to the
government, 'Look, we can't live on these low, minimum prices you've been
establishing,' because the secretary of agriculture had been lowering
the price floor from the Roosevelt era days, when it was set at the cost
of production, to a fairly low level. The corporations would say to the
government, 'Look, you can't raise the price you pay to farmers, because
we can't be competitive in the international market if you do that.' So
in the spirit of the Great Society, which [had] the mentality of spending
the public's money to kind of patch over a problem rather than confronting
the corporation challenge that was creating the problem, the government
chose a solution that they felt would satisfy everyone. They set the floor
price paid to farmers, the support loan rate, at a very low level. They
set it at the level the corporations told them they needed to be competitive.
And then they promised the farmers a cost of production level, which they
created through a new program called the 'Target Price Program,' so that
the loan rate became the price the corporations wanted, the target price
became the price the farmers said they needed to survive, and the difference
between the two would be made up by the taxpayers, in the form of a direct
payment to farmers called the 'subsidy payment.' Now this was a very clever
policy because it meant that the taxpayers were handing out money to farmers,
so they were called farm subsidies. But the purpose of those subsidies
was to keep farmers alive who were selling their crops to corporations
at prices far below the cost of production, which in fact meant that the
real subsidies were going to the corporations, and, ultimately, the consumers.
And from the 1970s until today, this has been essentially our program,
with one very large difference. In the early 1970s up through 1976, 1977,
1978, the spread--the cost to the government, the difference between the
target price and the loan rate--was not that large, and not that expensive.
But by the late 1970s, with the impact of budget deficits, which were
building, [the value of] the dollar, and many other factors, the cost
of maintaining this program, like the costs of maintaining other Great
Society programs, became prohibitive. And instead of the government asking
the question, 'How much do the farmers need to survive?' and making sure
that the payments to them were adequate to bring a fair income to farmers,
the Congress began asking the question, 'How much can we afford to spend
on the farmers?' And again, it indicates that the corporations were able
to shift the focus onto the farmers. They didn't ask, 'Well, how much
can we afford to cheapen the cost of wheat to Continental Bakeries and
Wonderbread?' And they essentially began reducing the target prices to
whatever levels they thought their budgets could handle, with no consideration
as to whether that would provide the cost of production. And in fact,
by the late 1970s, those target prices had been cut below the cost of
production.
MM: When a farmer gets a CCC loan does CCC take control of the
farmer's grain?
Ritchie: During the first nine months of each of those loans, it
is strictly a loan. Farmer[s] maintain the grain in their own bins, pay
for the storage, or maybe it is stored at a local elevator in town. When
the grain companies needed that grain, they would bid the price above
that level, farmers would then sell to the grain companies and repay the
loan with interest. Now as the government has dismantled supply management
programs and we've gotten larger and larger surpluses, grain companies
have been able to buy all the grain they need for a year out of surplus
stocks and essentially outlast the farmers, so that ... the grain companies
still aren't forced to buy, because they don't need the grain. So the
farmer then faces a choice, [and] generally the farmer can only choose
one option economically, which is that they look at their grain and [realize
that] the grain isn't worth enough today to sell it and repay the loan
with interest, therefore, the only other option is to forfeit that grain
to the government, in lieu of payment on that loan. This is what we call
a forfeiting of a loan. And at that moment the government must accept
the grain as payment for the loan. The government has acquired millions
and millions of bushels in recent years because we've had in the past
some very large crops produced, over and above what could be sold, and
they acquired those at very low prices, because the loan rate, or the
minimum rate, has been quite low. Today that grain has doubled in price
or value, so the government stands to make a fairly large profit on some
of that grain depending on what it's paid to store it. But in general
the program is designed in such a way as to attempt to avoid that. The
government should not be acquiring a lot of grain beyond what we normally
need to maintain emergency reserves, and in general the grain is typically
sold into the market and the loan is repaid.
MM: What are Payment-In-Kind (PIK) programs?
Ritchie: In the PIK program there are essentially two almost completely
different programs that have the same name. One was the very large acreage
reduction program of 1983, where because of enormous surpluses that had
built up in 1981 and 1982--the first two years of the Reagan administration--the
government, although their rhetoric is anti-government intervention day
in and day out, was forced to face reality, realize that the government
had to step in and help reduce production. The program was one where farmers
could sign up and not plant about half of their farm and they received
in return not cash but certificates which could be exchanged for grain
held by the government.... [N]ow, in subsequent years, this setaside kind
of program and the whole supply management element of that first PIK program
has been abandoned. But the concept of paying farmers in certificates
for grain has become a much more institutionalized part of the overall
government program. Today ... farmers receive a sheet of paper which says
you are entitled to so many dollars worth of grain, and at each county
elevator it says on the wall how much grain those certificates can buy
today. Now, in general, the government has been involved in a wide range
of land set-aside programs primarily for supply management purposes. And
again, the Reagan administration will day in and day out rail against
supply management as this 'lunatic,' 'Bolshevik,' idea. But the fact of
the matter is that the government is involved in supply management in
various ways and has been since the 1930s and before.
We tend to have two forms of supply management: one based on reducing
the number of acres or the number of cows or the number of production
units that you have, and the other form based on farmers actually reducing
the amount of milk or crops that they deliver to the marketing system.
One is called acreage based, the other quantity based. We've used different
programs--for example, in tobacco, there is a strict limit to how many
pounds of tobacco you can deliver, and that's how supply management is
accomplished. Or on wheat, it's an acreage reduction program. And there
are pros and cons to both systems. Certainly the quantitative one is more
precise and it has many environmental advantages. Within the acreage reduction
[approach] ... there are two kinds of acreage reduction programs: a paid
diversion, where farmers are paid to not grow certain land, and an unpaid
diversion. So, for example, the ability to use the CCC loan program is
generally extended only to farmers who sign up for and agree to set aside
a certain portion of their land. So, for example, next year the land set
aside is about 10 percent ... on wheat and corn. In prior years it's been
as high as 35 percent. In general, these diversions are unpaid. You get
the benefit of participating in the loan program and the target price
program if you set aside a certain portion of your land.
There is one very strong disadvantage to this program. If you are being
asked to set aside a certain portion of your land, and then you are going
to receive a subsidy on all the bushels you produce on the land that you
do farm, then there is a pressure for you to try to extract every bushel
possible from the land that you are farming. You can apply more chemicals
and fertilizers, for example; you can farm more intensively. But if you're
reducing your planted acres by 35 percent and then you're going to get
a target price payment from the government on every bushel you produce
on that 65 percent of the land that you're still farming, there's a very
strong incentive to farm more intensively, which generally means more
environmental damage.
The other kind of set-aside program is the paid diversion. Occasionally,
there will be paid diversions as part of the general farm program. But
really the most important and the most significant paid diversions are
newer programs that fall under the general category of conservation reserves.
We have these at both the federal and the state government level. What
this means is that on land that's deemed as fragile, or valuable from
an environmental or wildlife perspective, farmers are paid so much per
year over a long period of time to not farm the land. There may actually
be other elements--there may be conservation easements so that a certain
portion of the land remains in its exact same condition, but the point
is that in addition to the unpaid land diversions, which are primarily
in the supply management area, we are now developing a whole range of
paid land diversions, which are [the] conservation ... reserve kind of
program.
MM: Doesn't it seem that, for an administration so philosophically
committed to imposing market discipline, that supply management just makes
more common sense?
Ritchie: In fact, the way to frame the question is, Is the government's
role in supplying income to farmers directly from the taxpayers or through
price manipulation, or is the government's role more appropriate in helping
millions of farms to coordinate their production so that they're in line
with the needs of the small number of corporations who are going to take
their product?' Food and food security is much more central than anything
else we have to face. Supply management doesn't just mean helping farmers
get it together to reduce production in times of [surpluses], it means
maintaining a reserve large enough when we have a disaster like the drought
this year. What we're facing at the national level is that we're going
to have shortages and very sharp price increases next year, along with
being unable to meet the export demand that we've generated. Now, some
would say this is because of the drought, and certainly the drought is
a precipitating factor. But droughts are natural occurrences and they
happen all the time. Why we are going to face consumer shortages, price
increases and basically become again an unreliable export supplier is
not because of the drought--it's because the government failed to maintain
reserves large enough and in the right quality to then be able to manage
the supply in times of drought. So supply management has a logic in surplus
years and shortage years, a logic that the 'market,' pure and as defined
in college economic textbooks, simply cannot play. I think in terms of
farming, if farm policy is designed from a business point of view rather
than an economic theory point of view, it tends to be much more successful.
MM: Price supports were roughly $6 billion a year all through the
70s. Why are they $25 billion a year now?
Ritchie: Well, the cost of these programs is primarily the spread
between the target price and the loan rate, or the minimum price. Why
you see these sudden, very large jumps in the cost of farm programs is
that in the 1981 farm bill and in the 1985 farm bill--and again, these
tend to be the large, omnibus farm bills that set the general parameters
for four or five years at a time--both of these farm bills very drastically
reduced the price, the loan rate, the price that ended up being charged
to the grain corporations and the foreign buyers, while attempting to
maintain roughly the same target price level that they had before, because
of course in 1981 and 1985 farmers were in crisis, and to go into Congress
and argue that we have to cut the price to farmers sounded crazy. Of course
it was crazy, in fact it needs to be increased. In fact, the loan rate
on corn, which set the price, was lowered from roughly $2.60 to $1.70.
So you added about a dollar more 'subsidy' to each bushel of corn simply
by lowering that loan level roughly by one dollar.
MM: It sounds like 'supply-side farming.
Ritchie: It's totally supply-side farming. And, of course, one
of the problems with supply-side farming, like supply-side economics,
is that it has nothing to do with reality. For example, if you're Brazil,
or Thailand, or some country with a very large external debt, you're trying
to pay that debt by selling farm commodities into the world market. The
World Bank ... loans [countries] billions of dollars to produce corn,
rice, whatever, to sell on the world market to pay [its] bills. So the
U.S. comes along and cuts the price of rice in half, for example--we did
this. ... Thailand, which is the world's largest exporter and depends
on rice for its foreign currency to pay its bills, its foreign debt, and
to pay for its imports, suddenly saw its export earnings from rice cut
in half. Well, we had riots outside the U.S. embassy in Bangkok in April
of 1985 against the U.S. farm bill. Now, one might ask, why weren't there
riots in the U.S. against the farm bill? But it's because the government
of the United States had the money to shell out to farmers to basically
allow them to die slowly, quietly.... In Thailand it was [a] sudden cutting
of their export earnings in half and throwing their economy into chaos.
So, we were, year after year, from 1981 until today, lowering the price
that the corporations had to pay for the commodities, and trying to maintain
roughly the same price levels paid to farmers. And in each year, that
would add to the cost of farm programs.
MM: What is the biggest problem facing family farms today?
Ritchie: Income does not equal expenses. The shortage of income
this summer has a lot to do with the drought and the lack of any kind
of crop for the drought. It may also have to do with the fact that the
Reagan administration has abolished some of the farm programs, or attempted
to, which took income out of farmers' pockets. Even with the drought-induced
price increases that we've seen on the Chicago Board of Trade--and some
prices are now double what they were a year ago--even today, prices on
the Chicago Board of Trade for wheat and corn are below the cost of production,
and soybeans are slightly above the cost of production. This gives you
an indication of how far down prices were last year; they were roughly
half the cost of production. MM: In 1980 there were over 2.8 million farms.
How many farms have disappeared in the last eight years? Ritchie: In the
1980s, we will have lost between 700,000 and a million farms. We don't
know exactly what the figure will be or what the definition--how many
people will stay in their homes but not be able to farm their land. There
are just many things about it that we don't know. But we will lose approximately
one- third in the course of the 1980s.
MM: Does that include the large, corporate farms?
Ritchie: In the United States, we don't have very many of what you would
call 'agribusiness' farms. There are families who own very large chunks
of land, particularly in dry regions. The only sector where agribusiness
owned farms are really an important factor is in livestock. In those instance
you tend to have a very small number of poultry processors who contract,
generally with family farmers, but control it through the contract process.
But it's in beef where ... not only do three corporations control between
70 and 80 percent of retail beef sales, but those same three corporations
now, either directly or through direct feeding contracts, control about
half the production of beef. But it's not because they own huge tracts
of land where they run cows, it's because they own tracts of land where
they have feedlots with 100,000 cows and the feedlots buy this cheap grain
from the Midwest, thanks to the government subsidy program, and feed a
lot of the cows on their own.
MM: What can farmers do?
Ritchie: I think the model is the one that's common to all of our
society... When you have a problem which is based on a conflict of economic
interests, of class interests, as we have here with relations between
production agriculture, meaning farmers, and the corporations on both
sides, you have to look to the political arena as the place where you
can find some help in re-establishing the balance of power .. . In terms
of actual solutions, . farmers have sat down and gone over this throughout
the 1970s and 1980s, and there is basically one piece of legislation that
reincorporates cost of production price floors with supply management,
and that's the Harkin-Gephardt farm bill, as it's called now under the
current Congress. It will be updated and reintroduced ... in the next
Congress, perhaps with new sponsors. But essentially it says that we still
need ... a floor that keeps the price above a minimum [and] we need supply
management to protect our land and to keep surpluses from building up,
and we need some kind of ceiling to make sure that consumers are protected
by maintaining an adequate national food reserve. I think the thing that
has changed slightly, although it's been common since our country was
first colonized by Europeans, is that we're part of an international economy.
The United States has made many countries [that] buy their grain and food
supplies from us very dependent on us. We need to have adequate export
reserves, and food aid reserves, to meet those demands that we have created.
But, at the same time we are in an international market where countries
[which] are driven by the need to repay their foreign debt are willing
to underprice us no matter how low the price is, so the United States
cannot continue to try to operate on the international market based on
the idea that by being one penny cheaper we're going to take away the
market from everyone else, because that will never happen. It means that
we're going to have to shift from a confrontational stance of waging trade
wars against Brazil, Argentina, Europe and whatever, to a stance of being
in consultation with other exporters, being in consultation with importers
... establishing a system of some kind of minimum reference price globally
... negotiat[ing] [an] end to the trade war that we're engaged in over
market share, [and making] some kind of an arrangement on market share.
It is in this international area that perhaps there is some new ground
to be broken. . . . Farmers in the United States have been, since the
early 1980s, actively meeting with and strategizing together with farmers
in other countries, who basically all face the same problem, and proposing
very positive, creative, well-thought-out solutions--international agreement
solutions to some of these problems, which probably will get played out
in the GATT [General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade] negotiations, because
that happens to be the most important of these international government-to-government
negotiations going on at the moment.
MM: Can farmers band together and work cooperatively to cut crop
production in order to bring commodity prices up to the cost of production?
Ritchie: On a localized level, where you have a processor or supplier
who does not have the capacity to bring in a product from a distance,
from somewhere else, you have some potential local opportunities, although
you would put that processor at a hell of a disadvantage against other
people if you were to enforce higher prices for one processor and not
for the others. The problem is that two-thirds of the world's population
are farmers, and not all of those are subsistence farmers, producing for
themselves. A significant portion of them are, with the help of modern
technology and hybrids ... and World Bank financing, producing big crops.
Farmers banding together in this country to try to get a baker to [pay
a higher] price for wheat [would push] the baker to turn to Argentina
or to Australia or to wherever, and just buy the commodity and bring it
in. Then you'd have to have the government step in and control your borders,
which you have to have anyhow, but no matter how you describe the scenario,
your next thought is that there's a problem and there's going to have
to be intervention or laws at some level. On the other hand, we're not
about to let food corporations operate without government intervention
at the level of health and safety. We've had too much poisoning of people,
inadvertently and occasionally on purpose. We would never consider the
notion of government abandoning the food supply to the dictates of the
five or ten corporations which control the food production in this country.
Likewise, government getting out of agriculture or getting out of trade
or extracting itself, essentially means turning over the food supply to
the dozen corporations who control 90 percent of the world's food trade.
So when we talk about the government getting out of agriculture, what
we have to think about is who does that mean turning it over to? It certainly
doesn't mean turning it over to the two million farmers in the United
States who are all dispersed, living in different places. It doesn't mean
turning it over to the two-thirds of the world's population who are living
in the countryside and farming. What it means is turning it over to the
dozen corporations who control 90 percent of the world's food supply.
When we discuss trade and trade negotiations, we often use the terminology,
'the U.S.-Japan trade relations.' Or farmers are told that they are dependent
on exports. But what's missing is the fact that trade by definition is
a class matter. Corporations are engaged in trade, not countries, not
farmers, not consumers. In agriculture, trade isn't the province of the
country's two million farmers. It's controlled by 12 corporations, and
so trade negotiations are primarily to set the rules of conduct of the
dozen corporations involved in trade, and when we're discussing imports
and exports and all that, we have to always come back to the idea that,
in fact, we're discussing the activities of, literally, a dozen corporations.
So the idea that government can get out of agriculture is basically to
say that government should abandon agriculture to a dozen corporations
without any rules, regulations, or any intervening, and let the farmers
figure out if they have a way to unite in large enough blocks to confront
that multinational challenge.
MM: Will drought-induced commodity price increases help farmers?
Ritchie: Well, in terms of prices going up, we've seen a lot of
price increase at the retail level, and of course those products were
all made from grains and cereals that were bought last year under cheap
prices. Whatever we've seen in retail price increases already has no basis
in commodity price increases, and is strictly gouging, or, as [food processors
and retailers] call it, 'anticipatory' price increases. And, again, even
if the wheat in the loaf of bread was from this year's crop, where the
price has essentially doubled from last year, that would add three cents
to a dollar loaf of bread. I know bread in my local store has gone up
a lot more than that already, and they keep telling me it's because of
the drought. We're going to see price increases. But as we saw in 1972
and 1973, price increases far beyond anything justifiable in terms of
increases of commodity prices. But, has this been of some help to farmers?
Well, there are a lot of different ways to look at the question, but primarily,
there are a few instances where farmers got full crops and thus will have
a full crop times the new higher prices. But let me say again that [in
18 months] corn and wheat [almost] doubled in price, [and] are still below
the cost of production. So, anyone who got a full crop and is selling
corn for $2.65 is just losing a little less money. But, the point is that
there is going to be some unevenness, where some people lost their whole
crops and will have no income, some people lost half their crop and will
sell their crop at roughly twice the price. Some people got half the crop,
but that crop is very damaged in terms of quality. So although the Chicago
Board of Trade may say that corn is $2.65, the drought will have caused
damage to the quality so that there will be a 20 percent or more discount
off of that price.
MM: How have corporations responded to the Harkin-Gephardt bill
and other efforts to do something about the problems of family farms and
the high cost of farm support programs?
Ritchie: The corporations have shifted their strategy in the last
year to a new demand, which they call 'decoupling.' For a long time they
simply said, we'll get the government out of agriculture, but when it
became apparent that what that meant was spending $30 billion rather than
$6 billion on farm programs, the corporations realized that it couldn't
keep up like that forever. So they came up with a new theory. It's no
longer supply-side agriculture, it's the deregulation, the 'decoupling,'
the government abolishing of farm programs, and paying farmers kind of
a transition payment for four or five years to ease them out of this,
but from there on it's absolute, unbridled free market from here on out.
Decoupling gained a lot of credibility because it had addressed the question
of high government costs. If you abolish government payments over a five
year period of time, then year after year government payments will go
down. And you can simply argue that after a few years of adjustment the
free market and the invisible hand will everything right. Well, the drought
has essentially destroyed this argument by reminding people that for something
as necessary for human survival as food, the idea of just abolishing government
involvement and turning it over to 12 food corporations simply isn't going
to work. And that the idea that we can just let the free market be responsible
for ensuring that every year we have an adequate food supply obviously
is not going to work.
|