MULTINATIONAL MONITOR: In your study of the
1929 crash, you talked about how the U.S. economy had fundamental problems
then: bad income distribution, a floodtide of corporate larceny, problems
with the balance of trade, problems with the structure of the banks and
what you called bad 'economic intelligence.' Would you say that in any
of these or other ways the economy today is fundamentally unsound?
JOHN KENNETH GALBRAITH: There are broad similarities. We have had a worsening
of income distribution in these last years with tax reductions similar
in character to those of Mellon in the 1920s but larger in amount. In both
cases, one of the consequences was to push more money into the stock market.
It was supposed to go for building new enterprises, [but] in fact, a lot
of it went into speculation.
There are two even broader similarities. There
were then, as now, a lot of people in the market, a lot of institutions
in the market that thought prices would go up forever or ... that they
would get out themselves before it went down.... That is a fundamentally
unstable situation, because anything can trigger a rush to get out, in
October, 1929 and in October, 1987. But there were differences. The banking
system then was more fragile than now. Deposit insurance for both the banks
and the savings and loan associations does make a difference. There was,
at that time, no cushioning effect from unemployment compensation, old
age pensions, Social Security--which is now of substantial importance.
We had then a basically agricultural economy with nothing to prevent a
free fall in farm prices. Now agriculture is much less important with a
structure of farm income supports.... The most important difference is
that now there is a macroeconomic obligation by the government to come
to the support of the economy which didn't exist then. That is the legacy
of John Maynard Keynes, one that is equally important for right and left
and accepted by both.... My instinct was and is to believe that we face
a less serious situation than in 1929, but whether there will be a depression
or recession, we simply do not know.
MM: What are the implications of the international debt situation?
GALBRAITH: There are differences from 1929
in the international picture, two of which are of prime importance. In
1929, we were a creditor nation, not a debtor nation, so we were not subject
to the uncertainty of people in other countries who combined their fear
of what might happen to the stock market or real estate investments with
their fear of what might happen to the dollar. There is a double uncertainty
there, some of which was manifested on October 19, 1987. Secondly, there
is now a much heavier burden of international debt. There was a substantial
burden in 1929, both that of Latin America and also the so- called war
debts, but the international indebtedness is much more serious now and
is something on which there needs to be immediate action. And that means
a massive write-down.
MM: Is there a risk of an international banking crisis?
GALBRAITH: Could there be a run on the international banks that would shove
them under?
MM: Or some kind of shock which works itself through the banking
system.
GALBRAITH: There was such a run on Continental Illinois and that
was one of the reasons it had to be taken over. There was great uneasiness
on the part of its foreign depositors. But I would say the international
situation is just a larger extension of the national situation. I wouldn't
attribute any great additional importance to it.
MM: So even if the debt of the Latin countries and the other debtor nations is simply written off,
you don't think that has many dangerous implications for the international
situation?
GALBRAITH: If this puts some of our big banks in trouble, the
Federal Reserve and the FDIC [Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation] would
come to their rescue. This you can take as an established fact.
MM: Is there the possibility now for the emergence of any kind of countervailing
power on the international scene since labor has been so weakened by the
mobility of capital and the ability of companies to go overseas?
GALBRAITH: I don't see that likelihood, I confess. The labor movement is not in a
dynamic mode, and the internationalization of the labor movement is a rather
distant hope. I am less impressed by the operations of countervailing power
now than I was 35 years ago. At that time we had strong, domestically oriented
corporations and unions were getting strong. There was an apposition of
power which was very evident at that time. Since then, we have had the
emergence of Japan, Korea, the Pacific Basin countries and West Germany
dispersing the power that was once enjoyed by the steel companies and the
automobile companies and the chemical companies. We have discovered that
to have strong unions you need strong corporations. If you have weak corporations,
as in the case of the steel companies or Chrysler in the past, union strength
diminishes and unions are forced into not demanding higher wages but keeping
the company going with givebacks.
MM: But don't strong companies that still
enjoy some monopoly returns also have the opportunity to weaken their unions
simply by moving overseas or threatening to move overseas?
GALBRAITH: To some extent, yes. But we have learned in these last years that it is far
better for a union to have to contend with a strong company than a weak
one.
MM: Mobility of capital means that the labor pool for many companies
has expanded from a country to the world. What does that mean for the long-term
strength of unions?
GALBRAITH: If you are a union in El Paso, of which
there are not very many, you're handicapped severely if the plant jumps
across the river to Jaurez and not less so if it goes to Taiwan or Korea
or some subsidiary there. The long run effect is evident: it weakens the
union position here and in developed high-wage countries and, of course,
has some effect on wages in the countries where you are drawing people
out of very low-wage agriculture into low-wage but still higher-wage industry.
MM: Even though they are often subjected to a very severe government control
to prevent them from forming unions?
GALBRAITH: Unions are not all that
vulnerable. The extraordinary thing is that under most circumstances where
unions are needed they come into existence.
MM: How do you define a circumstance where a union is needed?
GALBRAITH: Where there is a clear exploitation
of the workers and privileged revenues are obtained for management and
owners.
MM: Why have unions not come into being in many Third World countries
where you have precisely that situation?
GALBRAITH: I would say that while
there is a lag there is a fairly reliable tendency for organization to
develop. This is true in much of Latin America and you see the beginnings
of it in Korea, Taiwan, even Hong Kong. There is no reason to think that
the process of union organization there will be slower than it was in the
United States. If you drop back 100 years you would have said there wasn't
much prospect here, either.
MM: Aren't workers exploited in the countries
in Central and South America, where you have large agro-export sectors
with large planters who run very profitable operations?
GALBRAITH: All experience shows that unionization is a lot more difficult in agriculture.
There are a variety of reasons. You have a less stable labor force, less
stable employment and the possibility of more cohesive action on the part
of employers than in the widely distributed agricultural labor force. There
is no question about it, agricultural workers are very hard to organize.
Also, agricultural employers have been more effective in using their political
influence against unions than industrial employers. We see that very clearly
in the United States. They have been much more effective at resisting the
minimum wage, and resisting the application of the National Labor Relations
Act than have employers in industry.
MM: Why have they been more successful?
GALBRAITH: [Partly] because they are more numerous, they swing more political
weight at state legislatures than Congress. There is a traditional fear
on the part of members of Congress and state legislators of the agricultural
influence.
MM: How important do you consider the fact that it is now possible
to shift fairly advanced high-tech production overseas?
GALBRAITH: We have discovered that technological change, which we had somehow assumed was
a special advantage of the United States or the highly developed countries,
really does move with lightning speed to new and lower-wage countries.
This will have a restraining effect on wages here which, indeed, we are
already seeing.
(balance of this article omitted here; unscannable)
|